(Tämä on vastaus eräälle finanssigurunettitutulleni, joka päivitteli minimipalkkahölmöilyn perässä sitä kuinka se näyttäisi olevan suora työnarvoteorian (labour theory of value, LTV) jatke. Analyysi oli sen verran itävaltahenkistä, että oli pakko tuoda sekin mukaan. Esimerkkinä käytettiin sitä kuinka vaikkapa finanssiprojektion luomiseen vaadittavassa työssä lisätyö itse asiassa voi epäajantasaisuuteen johtamisensa tähden aiheuttaa työn lopullisen arvon vähenemistä; siis ilmeisen epäkonveksia työn tarjontaan liittyvää esimerkkiä.)
I
think one aspect of econ education which helps proliferate that
nonsense is the way people conflate LTV and marginalist thinking. It's
obviously possible to do LTV in the modern,
Marshallian/Walrasian/whathaveyou framework, and when you do so,
you're essentially dealing with linear and homogeneous supply and
demand functions. When you jump into the marginalist frame, you
substitute certain laxer constraints, like diminishing marginal returns
and convexity, so that the framework becomes vastly more general.
Now,
you can go amiss there already: your above setup certainly isn't
convex. But the even nastier thing is that most people don't seem to
understand such details in their models, even if they do it the
mainstream model-building way.
What
hides the problem is how we usually do analysis Chicago style. To a
wannabe mathematician like me, the setup really is pretty simple: you
take all of your relevant functions, you go from them to differential
calculus (i.e. you do it "on the margin"), and then you formulate the
whole thing as an optimization problem under certain constraints. Under a
bunch of assumptions like convexity, the marginalist programme then
turns one-to-one into a distributed version of the method of Lagrange
multipliers: prices are the differentials, convexity of the feasibility
constraints and the optimands guarantees an efficient outcome, and
presto, you have a neat, mechanics-like framework you can use to keep
(even quantitative) tabs on your economic reasoning. So far so good, if
every Chicago style economist really thought about it this way, they'd
prolly understand what they really built into their models, and would
get the job done right.
The
problem is that nobody is taught the stuff that way. Instead the
fundamental assumptions are mentioned in passing, and then the
intuitions taught in econ 101 using Ricardian LTV are lifted right into
what we do on the margin. That works like a charm because reasoning on
the margin (i.e. with gradients) is formally about reasoning with a
local linearization of your overall problem. LTV is a fully linear
model, so whatever the classical economists could show using that,
applies as-is to the marginalization of the more general problem. So,
people easily get used to applying the intuitive shortcut of just
thinking about the problem in LTV terms. Just take a look at how people
mechanically apply option valuation formulae and you'll understand what I
mean.
It's
just that such reasoning only applies locally, and you need to mind
those pesky extra assumptions like global convexity if you want to say
something real about your whole model. Once you're used to working so
that you go through the ritual of writing down the same simplifying
assumptions over and over again, and then proceed to do LTV, you rarely
stop to think about what would happen if the problem actually *wasn't*
convex, so that it could have multiple equilibriums and such. Then
you're suddenly fucked when the real economy decides to do something
genuinely interesting for a change.
That's
just one example of the problem, by the way. There are probably dozens
of others out there. The second easy one I could point out is what Taleb
talks about in Black Swan and its groundwork: statistical assumptions.
Yeah, here too the basic setup is often general enough to capture the
real economy, but things like rational expectations theory and DSGE
modelling invariably go from the general to the specific case of
additive-Gaussian-independent even before the real analysis starts. And
so, again, your model breaks when the economy suddenly decides to not be
so well-behaved.
My
point is, I smell a bit of doctrinal disagreement here. Perhaps of the
Austrian/Chicago kind, dunno. Yet if I'm right, my answer is that I
believe those doing it Chicago style to be right in their basic
approach, but then often in over their heads with their own models and
prone to doing mindless calculation instead of real, inventive,
thoughtful math/logic. If they really understood what they were doing,
they wouldn't routinely be missing such patently obvious complications
as backward bending supply curves of labour, the downright obscene
heterogeneity and vectoriality of labour or human capital as factors,
or, say, systemic risk as an informational problem. They/we have all of
the logical and mathematical machinery in there to model pretty much
every economical problem elucidated thus far, but that machinery isn't
being taken advantage of nearly as fully as it should be; if you do, one
would immediately be led to do Austrian and (old) Keynesian type
qualitative reasoning, yet on a firmer mathematical-logical footing.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment